ethereum / EIPs

The Ethereum Improvement Proposal repository
https://eips.ethereum.org/
Creative Commons Zero v1.0 Universal
12.82k stars 5.24k forks source link

EIP 103 (Serenity): Blockchain rent #35

Closed vbuterin closed 2 years ago

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

Motivation

The Ethereum platform gives users access to a number of computational resources: particularly computational steps, memory, logs / bloom filter usage and permanent storage in the Ethereum state. For most of these resources, the gas system is roughly incentive-compatible, although price-fixing the exchange rates between these resources is, in the current framework, unfortunately required. Storage, however, is unique in that it is not ephemeral; once storage is filled, it must be stored by all full nodes forever until/if it is deliberately cleared. The cost of storage is bytes * time, but users are only paying for bytes.

A partial solution exists for Ethereum 1.0 in the form of the SSTORE clearing refund, where a user gets up to a net 10000 gas back for converting a filled storage slot into an empty slot. However, this approach is imperfect for two reasons:

  1. During a block where transaction inclusion demand does not reach the gas limit (or even where the opportunity-cost gasprice is cheaper than average), miners have the incentive to fill up storage slots so as to use them as a "bank" that expensive transactions can use to grant themselves additional gas at a time when gasprice is expensive; essentially, conducting inter-temporal gas arbitrage with the additional negative externality of requiring all full nodes to store extra data in the meantime.
  2. There is no incentive to use storage slots for a short period of time instead of a long period of time.

    Proposal

A proposal for solving this is to introduce "blockchain rent": rather than charging for bytes, actually charge for bytes * time. Here is a proposed protocol for doing so:

For example, suppose that TOTFEE[n] = n * 10 (ie. 10 wei per block per second), a block was last accessed in block 321070, the current block is 312085, the account has a pre-existing balance of 1000, and it only has two keys in storage: {"cow": "dog", "horse": "doge"}. We should have account.last_accessed = 321070 and account.total_storage_bytes = 3 + 3 + 5 + 4 = 15. Now, suppose we have a transaction that sends 10000 wei and, in the process of executing code, sets SSTORE("moose", "deer"). We compute:

The hardest challenge in this scheme is setting the TOTFEE function. One could set this to a static value (ie. TOTFEE[n] = c * n), but this is essentially a form of price-fixing and so is arguably hard to set in a way that is economically efficient. A somewhat more effective strategy is to set a space limit (arguably, this is no less reasonable than setting a gas limit), and targeting TOTFEE based on that value. For example, consider a policy where we have some function for setting a space limit L (eg. a flat L = 2**35 or a linearly growing L = 2**10 * (block.timestamp - genesis.timestamp)). Then, every block, we set TOTFEE[n] = TOTFEE[n-1] + 2**(20 * L / (L - total_state_size)) (ie. the fee is 2**20 wei ~= 0.001 shannon initially, then when the total state size increases to 5% of the maximum it doubles, when it increases to 10% of the maximum it doubles again, and so forth, with the doubling intervals decreasing in size and ultimately converging to a singularity at L). In theory, the amount of storage usage should increase until it hits an equilibrium equal to the marginal demand for storage at a supply somewhere less than L (in the case of the above example, roughly L / 2 is plausible); the main tradeoff to be made is in the steepness of the supply function. Steeper supply functions are more robust to mistakes made in the initial supply-function-setting process, but they also lead to more volatile rent charges.

Why should I want to support a proposal that adds in a "weird new tax" when storage usage per second is free now?

alexvandesande commented 8 years ago

In that proposal, the only way someone else can pay a contract's fees is to send money to it, correct? Should there be a way in which someone could send money to a contract but that the contract itself could not spend to anything other than fees? The scenario I'm thinking is one where someone created a contract that always does something with any money it received and keeps a balance of zero because it was programmed at a time that that shouldn't matter.

For example: say I build a contract that whenever anyone sends money to it, it automatically sends it 50% to Bob and 50% to Alice. It's a very useful contract for both Bob and Alice and they would like to keep it alive, but they can't send money to it in order to pay its fees because it will always forward all the deposits back to them. Even if the contract was programmed with the rent scenario in mind, how can Bob and Alice even know how much is enough for the contract? If say, the contract is programmed to keep 0.1% of anything that it forwards, and if storage costs are low and the contract is used a lot, it might create a scenario where the contract has fees to pay it's rent for the next 30 years and Bob and Alice cannot retrieve any of these funds..

About how to set the fee, can't that be left to the miners? Each contract might offer a price and miners choose to accept it or not and contracts can only be deleted if no miner in the last N blocks have accepted their rent?

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

In that proposal, the only way someone else can pay a contract's fees is to send money to it, correct?

Correct.

One option to solve the problem is for the contract to keep an internal "shadow balance" in storage, and then have a function for getting the difference between balance and shadow balance; someone wanting to send to the contract to fill it up would just call this function beforehand in order to learn how much to send, and then send that amount on top of what they were going to send.

About how to set the fee, can't that be left to the miners? Each contract might offer a price and miners choose to accept it or not and contracts can only be deleted if no miner in the last N blocks have accepted their rent?

The economics of this seem iffy; particularly, in this exact scheme, note that each miner receives 100% of the gain from including a contract but only pays a small fraction of the cost, so you'll get a much-larger-than-optimal quantity of contract inclusion.

chriseth commented 8 years ago

Having to keep contracts funded with ether all the time seems a bit awkward, although I can certainly see the need for and benefits of that. Which alternatives are there? Is it possible to pay for storage using gas? Can a contract perhaps deduct a certain amount of gas during the SSTORE that is used to hold the value in storage? Would it be possible to set up a "Storage fund contract" that holds a certain amount of ether but is used by a group of contracts which can then retrieve just the required amount of ether to fund their existence?

Correctly balancing storage and computation fee is also a major concern, because we do not really know how costs for storage and computing will change in the future. Also with EIP-101 in mind - would it make sense to use a "storage token" that is different from ether and used to pay for storage? Perhaps some of the logic could be moved into the storage token contract.

Oh and perhaps a side note: Contract code can be used to emulate storage: The only content of contract A's storage is a pointer to another contract P. It uses EXTCODECOPY to load data from P and whenever it wants to modify the data, it creates a new contract and updates the pointer. So I think we should also consider blockchain rent for code.

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

I suppose you can set up a system where a contract accumulates a "debt" of gas fees and that debt has to be paid off before you can interact with the contract (ie. same as above, except you do debt += fee, and when you send a transaction to a contract you do msg.gas -= min(debt, msg.gas); debt -= min(debt, msg.gas) first), and if the debt goes higher than the block gas limit then the contract can get deleted. However, any mechanism by which gas can be "stored" potentially allows for inter-temporal arbitrage (ie. paying down debts only when gas is marginally free); not sure about this but it might be the inevitable tradeoff for currency neutrality.

Another approach here is a hybrid strategy: allow temporary storage using some kind of ether or gas fees, at low cost, and then have permanent storage at high cost.

simondlr commented 8 years ago

Another approach here is a hybrid strategy: allow temporary storage using some kind of ether or gas fees, at low cost, and then have permanent storage at high cost.

I'm a fan of this. I feel there's something to be said for allowing some permanent storage on a blockchain. The "set & forget" nature of the "world computer" supported by various participants across the world is a big benefit. It's potentially dangerous to have some parts of a burgeoning contract ecosystem disappear, because rent wasn't paid (by whomever). Could lead to some cascading dapp failures. Also, who is set up to continue paying rent? If a build a dapp and rely on a contract that's paying rent, I want to be pretty damn well sure it's not going to drop off, or worse that I & others have to pay rent for it to keep going. If a developer says they will pay rent and they leave or die, will a community step up to continue paying rent?

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

I'm greatly in favor of some kind of blockchain rent. There's an odd morality in essentially forcing future users to pay for current use.

I agree with chriseth about contract code being used as storage. If this is a possibility, it would be better to create a specific perma-store opcode. (Call it owning a part of the blockchain rather than renting it.) However, what does it mean if a contract has some owning-storage and some renting-storage and it can't pay the rent? Does the whole thing cease to exist? Or just the rented data? Either could be a landmine for a DApp developer.

Every currently existing DApp will have to have a new incentive structure to self-perpetuate. For example, demanding a small fee when you use it. In itself this isn't bad, but nearly all old contracts will disintegrate short generous donations. In a hybrid system, we could rule that all old DApps have retroactively used owning-storage, and that new DApps can use renting-storage as they please.

If EIP 101 happens, how will this interact with the new ETH-contract? There will be a contract at 0x00... whose data is altered by the protocol and not by itself. I suppose the ping transaction could actually be a normal transaction sent to 0x00... but I'm not sure how the contract would be able to delete other contracts in an elegant manner.

PeterBorah commented 8 years ago

I'm pretty strongly opposed to this, unless there's absolutely no way around it. One of the unique properties of Ethereum is that contracts are trustworthy. I can build my contract on top of another one, and feel confident that that will continue to work.

In a blockchain rent world, that guarantee goes away. You now have to be paranoid that any contract you rely on might disappear at any time. Careful contracts will try to keep a fund around to rescue contracts they depend on, but that's never going to be a foolproof process. I have visions of a tiny utility contract used in a fundamental layer of contracts being forgotten about, and years later running out of funds, causing a quarter of active contracts to stop working. That's a failure you can't even recover from because of code immutability.

It also potentially opens up some attack vectors: I can call a contract a bunch of times, with the intention of filling up its storage and thereby making it too expensive to maintain. This costs me ether, of course, but it's only a one-time cost, while it might continue to cost the contract forever. And it might have disproportionate effects due to the cascading failure problem.

Finally, though probably least importantly, it adds a pretty serious amount of complexity to the process of creating a contract. Right now, the illusion that you're writing a normal web script is pretty good. After this change, there will be a whole host of complex issues around analyzing your code to determine future storage usage, checking dependencies to determine their likely reliability, etc.

PeterBorah commented 8 years ago

Instead, we should be aiming to keep contract storage below Moore's Law. If we need to increase storage costs to do so, so be it.

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

Ok, so it seems like parametrizing contract storage lifetime with 0 = current log, ∞ = current sstore and 0 < k < ∞ = new hybrid option might be a route worth exploring, perhaps where temp storage is encapsulated in a clear way so it isn't mistaken for permanent storage. For one trivial example of where storage with lifetime 1 might be useful, consider cheques.

PeterBorah commented 8 years ago

I think I don't understand what you mean by "lifetime 1". A cheque might go a long time without being cashed, so it will need a lifetime of longer than 1 block.

I'm definitely more open to a hybrid approach, though, if the unreliability of temporary storage is emphasized.

wanderer commented 8 years ago

on TOTFEE would it make sense to replace c as some function of the average gasPrice over x previous block?

EDIT: I kinda don't like targeting a total_state_size b/c we cannot predict hardware storage costs. But we can attempt infer the total system cost by the gasPrice.

alanpog commented 8 years ago

One of the unique properties of Ethereum is that contracts are trustworthy

I don't think trustworthiness in this context means necessarily permanent contracts, but I'd characterize it as having certainty, at any time Ta that the contract will still exist at time Tb, for the Tb that matters to you.

There's huge value in being able to predict, at contract inception, the future cost of rent (as a function of storage), and then design a contract that will provably survive under certain conditions, irrespective of exogenous variables like rent price.

One way to accomplish this certainty is through derivatives on the price of rent (simple forwards). But that would likely be too cumbersome for the average contract.

Another alternative is a rent insurance market where contracts can buy "lifetime" or at least long-dated rent for a fixed cost. Rent insurance contracts could even have variable storage allowances (i.e. fix a price for a flexible storage size, not a precise amount), as moral hazard can be significantly mitigated by the immutability of the contract's code. Of course insurance markets have tail risk and may need to be bailed out (or crash) if not regulated.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

@vbuterin Are we talking arbitrarily-settable (by the contract) k? I could see that being very useful. I'm working on a game where the players will probably not care about the state a week afterwards.

For the sake of argument, suppose you prepaid storage costs in current gas (i.e. SSTORE costs an additional (c * k) gas, with some (big) flat rate for permanent hosting). The system would have to have some way of detecting/clearing/deleting the unpaid, but at least it's reasonably possible to determine when a contract will lose its storage.

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

I think I don't understand what you mean by "lifetime 1". A cheque might go a long time without being cashed, so it will need a lifetime of longer than 1 block.

I am specifically referring to the use case of paying for contract functions in subcurrency; in this case cheques only need to last for long enough to persist between the parent and child execution, ie. just the block during which the ancestor transaction is included. For other cases, yes, cheques should probably have a medium-length expiry.

@vbuterin Are we talking arbitrarily-settable (by the contract) k?

Yes.

PeterBorah commented 8 years ago

That will work until scalability creates mandatory asynchrony. :)

It's worth pointing out that you as the user don't have control over when your transactions are included in a block. If there's a big gas price spike, or a networking issue, or just bad luck, you might miss even a deadline you thought was generous.

I am skeptical that self-destructing data is ever a good idea, but as long as there is the option for permanent data as well, I can just ignore the existence of the unreliable version, and advocate that others do the same, the way we ignore half of Javascript. Not ideal, but acceptable.

alanpog commented 8 years ago

Ok, so it seems like parametrizing contract storage lifetime with 0 = current log, ∞ = current sstore and 0 < k < ∞ = new hybrid option might be a route worth exploring

@vbuterin , wouldn't accepting anything different than k=0 just reduce the scale of (but not solve) the problem we have now (lack of incentive compatibility for storage) as any price for k>0 would be a guess that gets more uncertain as k -> ∞ ?

edit: what I mean by accepting is setting today a price for. In this sense the original EIP proposal would only accept k=0 pricing.

vbuterin commented 8 years ago

Yes, accepting anything other than k=0 would still lead to some degree of lack of incentive compatibility or inter-temporal arbitrage. But judging from comments, very many people consider this an acceptable price to pay for certainty.

alexvandesande commented 8 years ago

I have visions of a tiny utility contract used in a fundamental layer of contracts being forgotten about, and years later running out of funds, causing a quarter of active contracts to stop working.

This is something that can really happen, specially since solidity now supports libraries, which could create a cascading sheet of dependencies that no one is paying attention until one of the sub contracts get deleted.

simonjanin commented 8 years ago

I think this is a great proposal.

But there is something that bothers me a little, which is a related argument to @alanpog's : at the time of creation, a contract with permanent storage has a cost C[t], which will be linearly more expensive than renting one for a given amount of time. The thing is, if the gas prices change non-linearly, then this makes for a very asymmetrical situation in the long run -- where miners/validators would have to store the data of the first contract permanently essentially for free, while newly created contracts would pay non-linearly more; i.e. C[t+k] >= λ*(C[t])^(1 + ε) for ε > 0.

In a word, the argument is that if the gas prices change super-linearly over time, then this is not only unfair to the new miners/validators, it also makes it very difficult to insure against (insurance relies on costs being at most linear in the number of objects insured).

If we know for sure that only linear changes of gas prices are possible, then this is fine.

pipermerriam commented 8 years ago

I'd like to echo some of what @PeterBorah and @alexvandesande said.

I'm really hesitant about much of what this proposes. I'd like this a lot more if we keep a permanent storage system alongside a new ephemeral storage system. However, switching to a purely paid storage system opens up attack vectors and the potential for disastrous cascading failures and it isn't immediately clear to me how these issues are going to be resolvable.

niran commented 8 years ago

What if there were a way to revive an evicted contract? There's consensus on what the contract's state was when it was evicted, and if I'm willing to pay the gas costs and rent to get miners to store it and keep it around again, that could work around some of the terrifying scenarios where dependencies disappear. Transactions would just fail until someone revived the dependency contract.

If the revive mechanism is a bounty that any miner of future blocks can collect, most miners can continue to only store the active state while bounty hunter miners maintain quick access to older state that might be revived.

pipermerriam commented 8 years ago

What if there were a way to revive an evicted contract?

I'm not sure this solves anything. This assumes a lot of things about people paying attention to these things, as well as there being a benevolent source of funds to pay for ongoing storage.

alexvandesande commented 8 years ago

@alanpog

Another alternative is a rent insurance market where contracts can buy "lifetime" or at least long-dated rent for a fixed cost.

@chriseth

Also with EIP-101 in mind - would it make sense to use a "storage token" that is different from ether and used to pay for storage?

@vbuterin

I suppose you can set up a system where a contract accumulates a "debt" of gas fees and that debt has to be paid off before you can interact with the contract

Notice that all these things are being implemented in swarm/ipfs. It would probably be cautionary to see how these solutions pan out in the long term and then see how it can be used in the case of the blockchain. Swarm doesn't implement a token, but rather a debt system where nodes keep debts to each other and if they are past a limit and aren't paid these nodes are cut out. It also implements an insurance market where you can buy "promises to store" something and you risk a deposit if that ever goes offline.

If nodes could rely on swarm/ipfs instead of having full nodes then they could store locally only chunks of the blockchain that are often requested and leave other chunks on the "cloud". This could solve the issue of blockchain rent on the client level, instead of the protocol level.

niran commented 8 years ago

This assumes a lot of things about people paying attention to these things, as well as there being a benevolent source of funds to pay for ongoing storage.

The dapp pays attention to those things. The users are the benevolent source of funds. Consider a prediction market. Every transaction has fees, so the client software lets users know how much they're paying to take actions. If the user is attempting to redeem some of their winning shares but a required contract has been evicted, the client software includes the revival fees as part of the transaction fees. Alternatively, it lets the user participate in a crowdfund to revive the contract.

The perpetual blockchain storage world we live in is a seductive mirage. It is unsustainable to force future users to subsidize storage. Transaction costs in such a system will be higher than those in blockchains that charge rent, so it will be outcompeted. We are perfectly capable of building systems that collect enough revenue to fund their operations—this is how the whole world works.

Unrecoverable eviction does seem problematic, though.

nmushegian commented 8 years ago

throwing support behind @PeterBorah and @pipermerriam .

This EIP has the potential to introduce a lot of technical debt for DAOs working on ethereum.

The "rent vs own" discussion is the only one I would entertain, since then you could say all contracts prior to the upgrade own their storage and the semantics don't change. Even making ownership a special case for ETH 1.0 contracts is acceptable, as inelegant as that is.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

Thinking about @niran's idea for reviving contracts.

Let's call this process archiving. When a contract is left untouched (by whatever metric) for long enough it can be archived, at which point it is replaced in the state by a notice of the block the contract was archived. It can be added back by providing a SPV proof of that contract's state at the block it was archived. Note that we still can't remove the existence of the contract entirely from the state, because there needs to be some way of determining its last true state to prevent an attacker from providing an old but still techncially valid SPV proof.

I think the idea has merit, but I'm not sure what odd technical problems it might present.

@nmushegian: If we do go with ownership, I would discourage it being a special ETH-1.0 case. Otherwise, smart investors would create thousands of contracts before the upgrade, and sell their permastorage post-upgrade.

ethers commented 8 years ago

I am skeptical that self-destructing data is ever a good idea, but as long as there is the option for permanent data as well, I can just ignore the existence of the unreliable version, and advocate that others do the same, the way we ignore half of Javascript. Not ideal, but acceptable.

+1 behind @PeterBorah

niran commented 8 years ago

I'm not sure that it makes sense to have a portion of a contract's state be temporary. The behavior of a contract after a portion of its state has been deleted would be pretty hard to get right. It also complicates reviving the state (if that turns out to be feasible and desirable). Oh wait, no one is proposing this.

Contracts could opt in to temporary storage on creation, which would give them access to a cheaper storage opcode, but the entire contract gets archived if rent isn't paid.

As long as permanent storage remains expensive enough that any rational actor would choose Amazon Glacier instead, we avoid bloating the blockchain while allowing contracts to opt in to paying less for storage up front, but paying rent over time.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

If there are some contracts with permanent storage, and some without (because of grandfathering in old or some switch) it's still possible to mix the two by having a DApp store some of its data in the permastorage contract and some in the tempstorage contract.

If archiving is a thing, I think it would be best to have archiving be the sole method of blockchain bloat reduction. If there's a way to remove it completely from the state while remaining able to determine when it was removed (and how to prove it back into existence) even better.

alexvandesande commented 8 years ago

👍🏻 for figuring out an archiving process instead of rent. A contract that hasn't been called upon for more than X blocks could be entered in an "archive" state and the economics of processing archived transactions could be different and have different gas costs.

One could imagine that miners could ignore transactions (maybe for a small deposit?) that would call archived contracts, and the miners who process them could charge more (and get the deposits?) and then expose the storage and contract code to the next miners, who would then reincorporate the now-unarchived contract. But I'm not sure how effective this would be (if I call a transaction once every X blocks then it never gets archived) or what security implications it might have (censorship by prematurely archiving contracts?)..

etherReal commented 8 years ago

@alexvandesande :+1: to an "archive" system like this. Something like this would play well into sharding. If the game mechanics were such that exposing one chain or archive to another ("archaeology") would be a useful mining activity that was then further validated by the miners who "follow" a given "archaeologist".

chriseth commented 8 years ago

Yes, archiving sounds like a great idea! An incentivisation layer of how to re-activate archived contracts or move a certain set of archived contracts into a different shard can be engineered on top of the protocol, whose main benefit is that changes of this layer do not change the semantics of contracts. In general, "archiving" could also be applied to contracts for other reasons: If we change the implementation of the EVM, we could have a versioned EVM and "archive" contracts that use a very old version of the EVM in an incompatible way, so that not all validators have to have the implementations of all EVM versions in their code.

etherReal commented 8 years ago

@chriseth Future proof for the win. :) Each contract can live on it's chain and has a "shard address" which is locked to the evm that created it. Then as the protocol develops we don't get locked into compatibility restraints from bad decisions in a given evm or protocol instance.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

IMHO, there's actually not any need/way to force miners to pay for ignoring an archived contract. They already can ignore transactions with too little gasPrice, or because they want to censor it, or because they don't like that there's a 3 in the transaction's hash, or any other arbitrary reason. The hope is that some more understanding miner will include the transaction based on their own economic interest.

Suppose it took extra gas to call an archived contract. As long as it takes less than (gasPrice*revivalCost) in Swarm payments or computational resources to find the archive, the miner has an incentive to include the contract. (There's no way for the miner to know if the whole transaction will be worth it due to having no idea how much gas the archived contract will use.) If the miner ends up paying more to get the archive then the archive is worth, the miner loses some money, but it's still worth it to finish the transaction. If the miner can't find the archive at all, then the miner has lost money and can't finish the transaction. At that point the miner is probably justified in dropping the transaction from the pool altogether.

I realize now that the record doesn't need to be in the blockchain. Let each archiving increment the contract's archiveNonce, which is recorded in the state-change that archives the transaction. A miner proves that a revival is valid by providing an SPV proof of the archive being made in a former block. If another miner can prove that there is a later archive via the archiveNonce, the former block is considered invalid.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

Going with a "users pay rent" system in an archiving world, a contract call costs an additional (timeSinceLastRent * rentFee * spaceUsed) gas. An older contract costs more to call, but that's reasonable in a high-usage world (more popular contracts may be cached by the miners.) When that additional cost reaches the cost it would take to revive the contract, the additional cost is capped, but the contract may be archived.

In this system, revival costs scale linearly with the size of the contract. This may mean that sufficiently large contracts are practically impossible to revive, but this may not be a bad thing.

Unfortunately, this system may be naive in incentives for the users, because the first user to use a contract in a while will have to pay for the whole usage, whereas the next in the same block has it free. Perhaps the unpaid rent balance should be payed in parts by some function, such that the cost is spread between users.

An alarm clock system that automatically pays rent based on insurance bonds would not be difficult to implement.

alexvandesande commented 8 years ago

@smithgift the idea of a miner paying to ignore a transaction that was archived was only meant to create an incentive where the transaction is ignored the bigger the incentive to execute it. But your approach where costs scale linearly with the time since the transaction was last called could also work for that. The real purpose of ignoring archived transactions is actually so a miner can keep executing other transactions during the time it takes to retrieve the old contract from the archive.

I like where this is going. To be honest I'm not sure we even need to pay the "rent" anymore. A rational miner would execute any transaction where the fee paid was bigger than the cost of the contract + cost of reviving it.

On Fri, Nov 27, 2015 at 1:07 PM, Smithgift notifications@github.com wrote:

Going with a "users pay rent" system in an archiving world, a contract call costs an additional (timeSinceLastRent * rentFee * spaceUsed) gas. An older contract costs more to call, but that's reasonable in a high-usage world (more popular contracts may be cached by the miners.) When that additional cost reaches the cost it would take to revive the contract, the additional cost is capped, but the contract may be archived.

In this system, revival costs scale linearly with the size of the contract. This may mean that sufficiently large contracts are practically impossible to revive, but this may not be a bad thing.

Unfortunately, this system may be naive in incentives for the users, because the first user to use a contract in a while will have to pay for the whole usage, whereas the next in the same block has it free. Perhaps the unpaid rent balance should be payed in parts by some function, such that the cost is spread between users.

An alarm clock system that automatically pays rent based on insurance bonds would not be difficult to implement.

— Reply to this email directly or view it on GitHub https://github.com/ethereum/EIPs/issues/35#issuecomment-160156815.

Alex Van de Sande UX Designer

chriseth commented 8 years ago

Please take into account that (1) Serenity does not have proof of work, so the reward system might be a bit more complicated. For example it might be smaller if it takes the validator longer to revive the archived contract although that can be done asynchronously and included in the next block, so probably not an issue, but you get the point. (2) the system does not only have to work for the validators. Users want to know the full state of the revived contract, so the validator has to somehow make sure that the state is available through archive nodes or swarm and not only to itself.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

I was envisioning that the revival transaction would be an ordinary transaction that happens to call an old contract. From the EVM's perspective, it's just a lot more gas, the consensus is where the action happens.

Even simpler than the miner/validator finding the archive is forcing the user to provide the archive in the reviving transaction. If the user can't do that, how is the miner/validator supposed to?

In, re: (2) I was envisioning that the reviving transaction would include the full state of the revived contract. This does imply that reviving a contract is expensive state-wise (The blockchain has to now incorporate a merkle proof plus the contract's state, yet again.)

In, re: rent, if the cost of keeping the contract in the state is constant, then an attacker could fill a contract with junk over time and just keep pinging it to keep it in state. By making rent linear, this becomes increasingly expensive, until the contract is archived and forgotten by everyone except archive-everything nodes.

sillytuna commented 8 years ago

I'd like to back up Peter and Piper's views but I will admit to some bias. Several of the uses I'm looking at involve permanent data and libraries, surviving beyond perhaps the company that created them and accessed through constant funcs.

Some of it -could- move to to ipfs but some of it is suited to on chain queries. Besides, if the on chain bit was lost, it's a moot point.

These contracts come in two forms: 1) long term storage which is very infrequently read but must exist beyond any participant (notary) for a fixed number of years and 2) contracts containing a lot more per user data so which have regular writes and constant calls, then gradually dropping off on the write transactions. These need to persist indefinitely ideally, altho it may be possible to rig up a support model for small donations and alarm clocks to keep them alive. That requires an element of predictability.

It's critical that contracts and data can be made persistent for a fee imv. Without that we could see cascading failures, make it much harder to do some very useful (low per user storage) contracts, and cause confusion, problems or unpredictable costs for users.

If my contracts need to cost double for permanence in one form or other, that's a hit I would have to take. If permanence isn't an option, it's going to kill a number of use cases imho. That said, many contracts and data doesn't need to persist. What we should be doing is allowing both but with much greater incentives to the latter. Permanence should be added, not be the default.

jmlubin commented 8 years ago

In my opinion, all processing and storage on Ethereum should have an economic consequence. Developers must be conscious of dependencies including the costs to the network of these dependencies.

Rent should be charged for code and storage. There should be a (segregated?) pool of ETH that each contract maintains that pays this rent.

If the developer desires, a contract can implement an interface that enables a set of addresses (including the set of all addresses) to re-up that ETH pool.

@niran's archiving and reviving idea is a good one to rescue lapsed contracts. Pay the back taxes and it is revived. And perhaps you own or part-own it now?

People can set up "foundations" to perpetually support public good contracts. The costs will likely be small, especially in 2.0.

In Ethereum 2.0 these will all become more local decisions and mechanisms and may be handled with hybrid swarm/IPFS mechanisms. In fact, I think it likely that rent won't be implemented until the blockchain is stored using these kinds of mechanisms.

pipermerriam commented 8 years ago

This has gotten to be quite a thread of conversation. I'm going to attempt to summarize the ideas that have been presented thus far in hopes that we can pull this together into something actionable.

niran commented 8 years ago

I think @alexvandesande's comments lead to an important point: permanent storage without ongoing costs doesn't actually exist in today's Ethereum, nor can it ever. The optimal mining strategy is to prune state that is unprofitable to maintain. The simplest heuristic for this is to prune the state of the least recently used contracts. Miners who do this will ignore transactions that pay less than the cost of restoring that contract's state to accessible storage, either via fee payments or transfers from the contract's balance triggered by the transaction. If all miners use a similar strategy, blockchain rent would be imposed de facto: zero rent for transactions on recently used contracts, but the cost of restoring the contract's state for transactions on heuristically evicted contracts.

Formalizing rent or state archiving now seems unnecessary to me. Contract writers should be aware that permanent storage without ongoing costs is an illusion, so their users will have to pay a miner to restore the state if the contract doesn't have a built in economic mechanism to do so.

pipermerriam commented 8 years ago

permanent storage without ongoing costs doesn't actually exist in today's Ethereum, nor can it ever.

That is a very strong statement and I don't see the evidence to back it up. Please note that I'm not arguing the opposing point of view, but rather stating that we don't know how things will play out. It is very possible that either all storage will require ongoing rent or it may turn out that we can find mechanisms to allow truly permanent or effectively permanent storage.

niran commented 8 years ago

My evidence is just that there's no way to force a miner to store everything. They're going to store the data that makes them money, which is less than everything. The rest of the conclusions follow from this.

If storage becomes so cheap that it's always profitable to keep everything around, this stops being an issue. If we think this is unlikely, as I do, then contract authors need to prepare for it.

pipermerriam commented 8 years ago

A miner cannot include transactions in blocks which reference storage for contracts it's chosen to delete so it's easy to make the alternative argument that a rational miner figures out how to store that data.

I'm not saying that this is what will be what happens. Rather that we don't know what will happen and we should be careful when making very important decisions if our supporting reasoning is based on an assertion about what people will or will not do in the coming years. Predicting the future is difficult and technology changes the rules of the game quickly sometimes.

Smithgift commented 8 years ago

@niran: It's true that you can't force a miner to store anything. It's also impossible to force a miner to agree 2 ETH + 2 ETH = 4 ETH. The point of archiving being part of the consensus is that the protocol can punish miners who forgot contracts that everyone else has to remember.

While a non-formal rent system like this is elegant, there are issues. Other miners have to verify a transaction. If another miner creates a block using a pruned contract, they have three options:

  1. Take it on faith that the miner of the new block executed the contract accurately. This creates a kind of moral hazard should enough miners do this. (See: the unintentional forks from SPV mining in bitcoin recently.) Should the block be incorrect, and at least 51% are trusting or on the attacker's side, light clients may now be deluded as to what really happened in the contract, which could quickly spread across the entire state.
  2. Ignore the block until it's sufficiently deep. This may lead to effective censorship of an older contract if 51% of the miners will not mine on a chain that has a dubious block, which means that the chain is never deep enough for the block to become undubious. Even miners that trust/verify/don't care may still ignore the block on the basis that they don't want to be on the losing chain.
  3. Locate the archive of the contract and verify that it is a real block. This involves spending money and time for which the miner gets nothing in return, except, theoretically, being on the right chain if enough others do the same. A malicious miner could create wild goose chases for contracts that don't exist.

There's also the option of rejecting the block completely, in which case we have a fork.

Note also that any miner may pick any one of these strategies, The effects of all three being done in varying amounts may lead to instability, if nothing else. True, a modified p2p protocol where the miner shoves the contract's state along with the block may help some of these issues. But how does the miner know whether the other miners have the contract or not? If it guesses wrong, it either wastes both their time or the block is rejected.

NINJA EDIT: If the transaction is high value enough, a miner might reasonably assume that other miners dug up the same archive. There's troll potential in making an enormous contract, letting it be forgotten, then pinging with some ultra-expensive gas which turns out to be the equivalent of function() { throw; } The miner may not appreciate the small amount of gas he got from it relative to the expense of getting it.

Actually, the true cost of revival is (pretending we live in a world with equal-powered miners) something like (number of miners * cost of acquiring the archive), because the effective reward is averaged between every miner. This is true of every revival system where the user does not provide the contract's state.

Non-formal rent seems to have merit, but something about it makes me uneasy.

etherReal commented 8 years ago

You can't have everything where would you put it?

:+1: to @Smithgift above.

“My evidence is just that there's no way to force a miner to store everything. They're going to store the data that makes them money, which is less than everything. The rest of the conclusions follow from this.”

If we agree with @niran and assume that miners will drop what they can't profit from and then follow @jmlubin's reasoning to advocate rent or back taxes then there will be contracts that sink down the archive layers into the distant and potentially inaccessible past, whether or not they have a use to someone or everyone. Contract availability will be a function not of utility or gas value to any given user but to the ability to pay to embed rent in the contract or to stump up an ever increasing resurrection fee.

We may then see sets of contracts huddled in shop doorways with “will work for food” signs all along the block chain. This is a great way to bring back a class division justified by “meritocracy”, you might think of it as censorship of the poor.

I think the solution to this problem should be incorporated into Casper. The solution below offers an off the top of my head way to incorporate a redistribution of ether into the mechanics of the mining game.

To Illustrate my point lets look at this from a highly non technical metaphorical perspective:-

Let us take the underlying market mechanics and put it in the context of a real world market.

[Like mining,] Employment is administered as a 'market'. People get rewarded for their work based on the (market embedded) remuneration strategy of their employers. On the one hand there is competition between applicants to fill these roles and on the other the demand of employers to get a given job done. This hides a host of assumptions and game mechanics (e.g. class interests / cultural norms etc.) that are not explicit in the market mechanism itself.

There is an alternative method of administering work in the physical world called the Balanced Job Complex, which I shall now describe as it might be implemented for archiving or sharding in Casper.

As part of their 'bond' each Miner must prove that they have stored a randomly assigned share of archiving tasks (Assuming this to be potentially computationally and storage expensive but may never be rewarded) as some proportion of their “work”. All miners are also given a random share of the most regularly rewarding and empowering tasks (contracts that are very popular). Mining is thus coordinated with everyone's involvement in both 'rewarding' and 'burdensome' tasks on a “fair” basis. The burdens and benefits of work are then allotted by Casper so that each nodes ability to participate in democratic decision-making within the network resists class division.

This will not prevent the data base growing infinitely big but it will mean that at least in the medium term (for the next 5 years?) no mater how big the entirety of the system grows, not every full node has to store all of it.

P.S. I am sure this is a forking nightmare but it's all I've got.

sillytuna commented 8 years ago

Rent should be charged for code and storage. There should be a (segregated?) pool of ETH that >each contract maintains that pays this rent.

Here's an example use case where it has to be clear how it'll work:

A contract containing a large number of 'users' is much more space efficient than a contract per registration. User data could be 32-128 bytes depending upon the details.

Who pays for the cost of the now large contract persisting? Each individual user item, which could be a Solidity array, isn't going to be individually tracked, it's an all or nothing affair I would assume. The contract could store additional data for who has paid renewal fees, and could then zero out anyone who hasn't (has its own implications in terms of data organisation - there is no simple/cheap way to 'compact' a solidity array for example IIRC).

Can we charge each user up front 'renewal' fees to guarantee availability for e.g. 7 years, an example period for documentation retention?

Who is paid those fees and how predictable will they be?

Will centralised services be needed to issue reminders and track renewal requirements, similar to domain name services?

What about where the blockchain is queried for older data only? Will we have archive nodes which allow that for some kind of fee?

What about the risk of cascaded failures - how can we be very transparent about renewal requirements for libraries and utilities? It's all very well saying we could each set up a kind of on-chain foundation but I think that's rather pie in the sky because it takes organisation - people aren't that organised.

I'm also concerned that decentralised contracts will then have the risk that they only work with centralised patronage.

niran commented 8 years ago

@Smithgift Great points.

The point of archiving being part of the consensus is that the protocol can punish miners who forgot contracts that everyone else has to remember.

Formal archival just removes the incentive to ignore a restored contract by providing the entire state of the contract when the contract is restored so there's no need for all the miners to fetch it on their own. This doesn't have to occur at the consensus level, though. It can be replicated in contract code. If there's a hint that no old data besides headers is necessary to validate the transaction, there's no incentive to either blindly trust or avoid the transaction when mining new blocks. Contract writers could set a flag on functions that causes them to terminate and consume all of the provided gas if the function attempts to read from the contract's storage. Miners could safely execute these even if they've discarded the state.

Formal rent provides an avenue for an incentive to keep the state around, but there's no guarantee that the contract will pay rent. Miners will still discard the state of contracts they don't expect to pay rent, even if it's formalized. Might as well avoid formalizing it and let miners and contract writers coevolve to a point where they both have accurate expectations about what state will be kept locally and how profitable a contract's state will be.

chriseth commented 8 years ago

Just a random thought about the cost of archiving (sorry if it has been brought up already):

Since all miners / validators have to execute all transactions, the reward for executing an opcode is currently set to be X * n, where X is the cost to execute it by a single miner and n is the number of miners. Assuming equal mining power and reward being equal to the actual costs, this evens out the costs on average for all miners.

So our general model is "mining reward equals overall network costs".

Of course storage has costs over time, because it cannot be reused, and thus our fixed price per SSTORE model is flawed - the reason for this EIP.

Reviving contracts from an archive is a different story, though: For keeping a contract archived, it is enough if only a small number of archive nodes keep the contract. Also the influence of time is not as important anymore - it costs money to keep disks working, but it is much cheaper if you do not expect the data to be accessed often. So we have the interesting fact that the gas costs of an opcode should scale with the size of the network, but the costs for keeping data archived scales with time and not with the number of nodes, and I would argue that the time-scaling factor is even quite low compared to the fixed costs.

Now let us look at the costs for retrieving the data from an archive: Of course, not all full nodes will need to retrieve the data from their own archive, rather they will initially all use the tiny number of archive nodes but the data will replicate quite fast through the network - in the same way a newly created block will spread. Spreading data in the network scales extremely well with the number of nodes (see bittorrent), so again: The costs for reviving a contract can be considered constant.

Of course I am assuming that the archive data is correctly merkle-hashed and cannot be spoofed, but that is easy to achieve in a logarithmically scaling way.

So unless I am mistaken, I would say that almost-permanent storage of data at (comparatively) almost no cost is quite possible.